This colloquium was presented by Sangamitra Ramachander, PhD student, Oxford university. This is an early draft, and the paper may change significantly.
This is based on findings from the Teleuse@BOP3 project.
The context is that in a variety of sectors, private sector do not have prior experience in serving low income and rural markets; however, now the entering. They have to decide on an appropriate price such that it is still profitable. How should one set the price? One can be through actually asking customers how much they would willing to pay. Useful when they don’t know much about what the product is about. However, respondents think that the ultimate price may be higher than what they state, hence they could be biased in their responses. However, such a method remains popular.
There has been a huge increase in people using such methods, even despite criticisms.
W.r.t. the Teleuse@BOP study, respondents were given a payment ladder to mobile users, in the form of a diagram, which denote different prices, and asking how many minutes they would use at each level (not only mobile use, but any type of phone). This paper looked at only mobile owners, not non-owning mobile users. A limitation is that every reduction in circle represents a 20% reduction, however respondents may not know that and they could perceive it in any way that they want.
Advantages: Respondents are existing mobile users; non-numerical form facilitates comparison across countries; data is of a continuous form since the commodity is divisible (in terms of number of mobile minutes used at different prices)
Limitation: ‘Meaning’ of each diagram (strictly 20%) could have been interpreted differently across respondents. Assumes respondents calculate new price (20% cut) and estimate new corresponding consumption independently. Arguably a strong assumption given profile of respondents – BOP population
The problem: If interpretations are different across respondents on magnitude of price change, responses not comparable.
How we construct this:
- Consider the first two diagrams only (a ‘small change’ from the current price)
- If respondents change consumption – they are elastic (coded 1), and if not, they are inelastic (coded 0)
Why is a binary outcome variable better?
- Assumes only that respondents understood direction of price change (not magnitude)
- Responses based on ‘small change’ in price is likely to increase precision
Clean the data: eliminating responses reflecting a lack of understanding
- The outcome equation: ‘Is demand elastic to price change?’; this outcome is observable only if respondents own a mobile phone (binary outcome variable)
- The selection equation: ‘adoption’ equation (DeSilva et al.) – Modeling likelihood of mobile ownership (also a probit)
- The model also allows more theoretical exploration by separating adoption and use variables
- Same variable might affect the two equations differently (example income)
- There might be variables relevant to one and not the other
- Demographic characteristics (age, gender, education, income)
- Perceived benefits of mobile adoption (emergency, social and economic)
- Top five other individuals most frequently contacted who own a mobile (‘social influence’)
- Ownership of other electronic goods in the household (tv and radio)
- Access to electricity
- Remoteness of location
- Country dummies
- Cost minimizing techniques (use of mobile for missed calls or incoming calls)
- Loyalty to service provider – those who say they are unlikely to switch to other service providers
- Ownership of multiple SIM cards
- Level of existing use (last mobile top up amount)
- Purposes of existing use (services in the areas of health, govt, agri/fishing, general info, competitions)
- Top five other individuals most frequently contacted who own a mobile
- Perceived benefits of mobile adoption (emergency, social and economic) (based on deSilva mobile adoption paper)
- Demographic characteristics (age, gender, education, income)
- Access to electricity
- Remoteness of location
- Country dummies
Rohan – you refer to “savvy” users. who are they? you refer to them as those who have more contacts (top 5) with mobile phones. they are not necessarily those more sophisticated, they are just people who are more electronically connected. replace this word with someone more plausible.
HeckProb estimation of price elasticity of demand: significant variables – switching providers (those not likely to switch are more inelastic), number of sims, greater use in times of emergency (more elastic), top 5 contacts and competition.
Findings: Demand is elastic among more savvy users and those with more limited use:
-
- Savvy users: Those who report a greater number of close contacts who own a mobile phone and those who use the mobile phone to participate in ‘competitions’ (the most popular among the list of services)
- Limited users: Those who attribute a higher value to the emergency uses of a mobile
- Those who say they would not switch to other service providers are 22% more likely to have demand that is inelastic to price change, holding all other covariates at their mean values
- A unit increase in the number of SIM cards owned increases the likelihood of demand that is price elastic by 11%, holding all other factors constant at their mean values
Concluding thoughts:
- Latent demand exists among more savvy/active users and more limited (contingency) users since both have demand that is price elastic
- However, users can easily switch between service providers
- Competing on price can therefore lead to price wars, which could threaten survival particularly since profit margins are likely to be low in BOP markets
- Loyalty to a service provider on the other hand appears to make demand relatively inelastic
- Non price strategies therefore might be more effective in the long run for customer retention and survival
Rohan – the last slide suggests that we are interested in how companies can make more or less money; rather our focus is getting more at the BOP connected.
Sangamitra – i think if we are moving to private sector delivery of services of BOP useres, they have to survive, and hence how does one make sure that those who enter this market remain profitable. Then should this sector be regulated? These businesses should not resort to price cutting in such a way that drives companies out of business.
Christoph – i have conceptual issues.
Sangamitra – we don’t have panel data. With that limitation, we have use such models (contingent evaluation) to arrive at conclusions. w e are not looking at the magnitude of change, only whether it is elastic and inelastic. since we don’t know whether they understood the question
christoph – we can only say whether they would be willing to change or not, not elasticity.
Sangamitra – that’s usually an limitation of binary models
christoph – conclusions get falsified if one cannot talk about degree of elasticity. for those who don’t change use in response to price change, how come? it could either be because they didn’t answer the question, maybe were they not so poor.
christoph – it could be that the model is not relevant. also, if there was anything that looked nonsensical, i would check if there were outliers
sangamitra – i am less surprised by these findings; but it would be good to examine the profiles of those elastic versus those non-elastic.
sangamitra – what would be the regulator’s response to such findings? how would this relate to them?
nirmali – could setting some form a minimum price be a possible solution?
helani – yes, but situation not so simple.
ayesh – some form of bundling or price loyalty?
sangamitra – yes.
ayesh – does it have implications on mobile number portability?
sangamitra – yes;
helani -it would be interesting to see if findings differ between pakistan where you can port numbers and those who don’t.
helani – however pakistan also has some of the highest multi-SIM ownership
ayesh – but qualitatives also showed that different in network coverage was one of the reasons why some of the multi SIMS.
helani – has anyone done analysis among those who don’t own mobile phones?
sangamitra – there is an estimate which shows the degree of correlation between unobservable factors in the model – we found that it was significantly negative; however, one must be cautious about making statements about such findings.
sangamitra – a lot of recent articles cite the Heckman model.
3 Comments
Rohan Samarajiva
while the slides referred to “savvy” mobile owners, in the actual presentation Sangamitra changed it to mobile-connected owners. I think it’s also important to clarify that the entire discussion is limited to mobile owner-users, not non-owner users. Therefore, quite a lot of the references in the slides and notes need to be replaced by owner-users, or owners.
Sangamitra Ramachander
Thanks to everybody who could attend for very useful feedback and discussions on the potential policy implications.
Workshop: Digital Tools for Strengthening Public Discourse
Today, LIRNEasia hosted a workshop to launch digital tools created by Watchdog Sri Lanka, funded by GIZ’s Strengthening Social Cohesion and Peace in Sri Lanka (SCOPE) programme. Researchers, practitioners, activists and journalists attended to learn about these tools, and how they can potentially help them in their own lines of work.
Election Misinformation in Sri Lanka: Report Summary
Election misinformation poses a credible threat to Sri Lanka’s democracy. While it is expected that any electorate hardly operates with perfect information, our research finds that the presence of an election misinformation industry in Sri Lanka producing and disseminating viral false assertions has the potential to distort constituents’ information diets and sway their electoral choices.
Election Misinformation in South and South-East Asia: Report Summary
A powerful weapon in a time of global democratic backsliding, election misinformation may undermine democracy via a range of mechanisms. Election misinformation may influence an electorate to cast their ballots for candidates they otherwise might not have on the basis of incorrect information about a country’s economy, the candidates, or some other phenomenon.
Links
User Login
Themes
Social
Twitter
Facebook
RSS Feed
Contact
12, Balcombe Place, Colombo 08
Sri Lanka
+94 (0)11 267 1160
+94 (0)11 267 5212
info [at] lirneasia [dot] net
Copyright © 2024 LIRNEasia
a regional ICT policy and regulation think tank active across the Asia Pacific